UPDATE: I see Dmitri is retweeting all the odd-numbered parts of this series (his), but not the even-numbered parts (mine). OK... but do yourself a favor: read my responses. See for yourself if Dmitri's arguments hold up.
I feel quite confident that you'll find he doesn't have much cause to believe he got the better of me in this exchange. But you be the judge.
Dmitri Mehlhorn and I continue our exchange about charter schools.
Leave your thoughts in the comments below. My final reply will be up shortly.
* * *
Five Questions for Charter Critics
Jazzman-Mehlhorn Episode V
Reform
skeptic Jersey Jazzman is hosting a debate about charter schools. He and I have
spent 4 posts and about 10,000 words discussing the past few years’ worth of
research by charter advocates, detractors, and academics. We will probably have
a “long tail” of comments in social media, but this is the final formal
installment of my appeals to Jazzman and the other skeptics who have engaged over
the past year or so, including Sue Alexander, Dr. John Thompson, Deb Stahl, Jack
Covey, Ajay Srikanth, Daniel Katz, Greg Clark, Mindy Rosier, Ben Spielberg,
Peter Greene, Ben Faber, Randi Weingarten, Dr. Bruce Baker, Gail Richmond, Ed
Harris, Jennifer Berkshire, and others.
If you’re up for
it, I have five questions for all of you. Of course, this is not an exhaustive
list – we could talk for years about test scores, poverty, fixed costs, and
other issues. But in the spirit of trying to make progress in at least some
areas, I’d be grateful for your honest take in these five areas, not conflated
with other issues.
(1) Jazzman, why don’t TPS test results go down as charters
expand?
Mark,
the skeptics’ most common and most powerful arguments involve “skimming.” Compared
to TPS [traditional public schools], these arguments claim that charter populations qualify more for reduced-price
rather than free lunch (i.e., mild poverty rather than extreme poverty);
charters push kids out more often; charters don’t always backfill open seats; charters
deliver peer groups rather than better education; charters don’t serve as many
SPED [special education] or severe SPED students; charters only serve students whose parents are
motivated enough to apply; etc. These claims have elements of truth, but the
key question is their aggregate impact including offsetting issues.
Mark, do you
acknowledge the role this claim plays in the architecture of charter skepticism?
After all, if skeptics are right on this issue, charter test-score gains are
illusory, and thus charter expansion will hurt TPS by leaving them with a
hard-to-teach cohort. If skeptics are wrong, then the charters’ test-score
gains result from something the charters are doing, and charter expansion does
not damage TPS by leaving them with a hard-to-teach cohort.[i]
Mark,
as you know, both sides have invested heavily in studying TPS student
achievement as choice expands. I won’t revisit all prior posts, but you know
I’m looking at Washington DC; New Orleans; Florida; some boroughs in New York
City; and some districts in Texas.
Mark, where is the
evidence backing up the idea that hard-to-teach cohorts will be increasingly concentrated
in TPS, driving down results? Is it possible for you to acknowledge the weight
of the current evidence on this subject?
Will you have the courage to articulate a testable explanation for why
the facts have repeatedly been the opposite of skeptics’ predicted
results?
(2) Jazzman, why aren’t race and history relevant to the burden of
proof here?
In your most
recent piece, Mark, you characterized my burden of proof argument as follows: “if
someone can gather up a few parents who want something, they should get it,
absent a compelling reason that they shouldn’t.” I would like to better understand
why you and other skeptics are so quick to dismiss the racial and historical
issues suggest a different presumption.
Let’s start with race.
On average, graduation rates, test scores, and other metrics suggest that African
American students and Hispanic students are poorly served in existing TPS,
especially by comparison with white, Jewish, and Asian students. Parents in
African American and Hispanic communities often speak out on the topic of
school choice, in interviews, focus groups, polls, and charter applications. I
have cited some of the results in previous posts, but the short version is a
lot of these parents really want more charter schools. Tens of thousands of parents (or more),
who bear the legacy effects of centuries of state-sponsored racism, should not
be dismissed as “a few parents” who’ve been “gathered up” by “someone.” Their
agency and their numbers suggest a different presumption.
Turning from race
to history, your post refers to Russell’s Teapot. That is a perfect frame for what
many parents of color say. For white, Jewish, and Asian parents in TPS, choice
and the threat of choice long ago enabled meaningful control over their
children’s schools. Thus, current anti-charter laws have unique and disparate
force among low-income black and Hispanic parents, who become compelled to send
their children to struggling TPS. The
anti-charter policy therefore amounts to the following: “I, Jersey Jazzman,
offer you the Russell’s Teapot monopoly public school system. This public
school system is a century-old experiment that has not yet delivered results
for your community. We cannot give up, however, until we try to supplement
those schools with more social services, more resources, and other innovations.
Until every possible test has been tried (other than charter schools of course),
you will be required to send your community’s children to these TPS into the
infinite future.”
Mark,
this is not a choice between two impossible-to-assess claims.
[ii] As you know, we are not talking about
authorizing a specific charter, but rather laws that limit the expansion of
*any* charters. As you note, our nation has gathered considerable evidence
about this question.
We know that
nonprofit and private actors compete with public actors for public dollars in
other sectors, including healthcare, energy, and military procurement. We know
that wealthy parents already have extensive school choice.
In light of that, why isn’t the burden
of proof on the monopoly public school system, which overwhelmingly employs
relatively prosperous white people, and which was constructed without
meaningful input from (and often deliberately in opposition to) communities of
color?
(3) Jazzman, why don’t you push for good charters?
You
seem to agree that the best charter school chains can deliver results. Why don’t you push to replace charter
caps and limits, like we have here in Virginia, with enlightened charter
authorization policies like those of Boston?
(4) Jazzman, how much improvement would be enough?
If
you are open to facts, I am trying to understand what evidence would be
sufficient for you to prove the theory that charters actually work better than
TPS for low-income students of color.
You
dismiss the CREDO 2015 results in a few ways, but I think you’re missing the
forest for the trees. To try to clarify the issue here, let me try to stipulate
as many of your objections as possible.
First, let’s talk
about whether a fraction of a standard deviation is meaningful. You don’t like my healthcare example,
and we can’t seem to agree on human height,[iii]
so let’s use the market returns example that you approved. You said that a
difference of 0.1 standard deviations was not a big deal, because “if my
investment goal is to make a million dollars, getting $275 over $232 is not of
any practical significance for me”
(emphasis yours). Jazzman, that’s more than an 18% difference in end-of-period
wealth, and I used a starting number of $100 just to make the math obvious. The
median net worth of a household in America today is about
$81,000; using that as a starting investment delivers a 10-year difference of
$35,000 in extra wealth. And remember, 10 years still a shorter period of time
than a child spends in K-12 schools.
That said, you
suggest that 0.1 or .11 standard deviations is not the right benchmark, because
those are the aggregate average gains Hispanic ELL students, who seem to
benefit especially from charter schools.[iv]
So, let’s broaden to include all black and Hispanic students in poverty, who
benefit by less in math (.08 and .07) and reading (.06 and .04).[v] If you apply those numbers to the
financial market calculations from the prior paragraph, you get gains of ~
$27,000; $24,000; $20,000; and $13,000.
To me, none of those are small potatoes, but the real point is that it
depends on your perspective. Parents and policy-makers would certainly be on
safe ground in concluding that gains of that magnitude are worth embracing. Any
instrument that reliably delivered those kinds of gains would instantly become
the industry norm on Wall Street.
You
argue that the effect sizes of charter schools are merely “a few more bubbles
filled in correctly.” Yet Mark, a few bubbles per year on average, across a
large population, represents marginal additional mastery every single year.
It’s not a perfect or complete measure, but it may just be the difference for a
kid on the edge. Maybe the best way to frame
it is not that students advance faster; rather, maybe it’s that they don’t fall
behind. Either way, even if you and many others do not think that those bubbles
matter, millions of educators and parents care about them.
All
of which leads back to the original question: how much would be enough? What would charter schools have to show
you for you to accept the theory that these schools, because they do not have
to deal with the union contracts and other bureaucratic hurdles, actually
deliver better results for low-income children of color?
(5) Jazzman, do we already have some areas of agreement? If so, what do
they mean?
For policy-makers
interested in choice policy, it seems as though we might agree on a few
things. Having read your work, and
that of many other conscientious charter skeptics, I thought I’d take a stab at
areas of agreement, and see if you could agree to any of them, or articulate an
alternative package of agreements, and then suggest what policy-makers might
learn from those areas of choice when deciding whether or not to maintain
charter caps.
For my part, I
agree that for suburban areas, and for white, English speaking, prosperous
children, traditional public schools currently perform as well as charter
schools, or better. I agree further that, even for poor students facing
residential segregation, charters alone will not eliminate the achievement gap
between the children of wealthy families and the children of poor families
(although charters will at least start to equalize the narrow issue of school
choice, which wealthy families have and these families do not). I agree that
some charter schools have been much more effective than others, and that
charter authorizers should therefore be careful in expanding charters and aggressive
in closing them. I agree that numeracy and literacy, as measured by test
scores, are not a complete measure of student achievement or school
performance, and that therefore over time we need to monitor lifetime student
outcomes. I certainly agree that schools alone
won’t solve all of humanity’s problems, from wealth inequality to violence to
sickness. I also agree that more
money, if spent properly on students, could help students obtain better
outcomes.
I
have not been able to identify your explicit concessions, as they often appear
as caveats or rebuttals. I
believe, however, that you acknowledge the shameful history of American
traditional public schools, including the consequences of residential
segregation, and the racial motives of public actors who built the modern K-12
system from the late 1800s to the early 1900s. I am confident you condemn
situations where TPS student discipline is turned over to physically violent
police, or where teachers are abusive, just as I would condemn those situations
in charter or private schools. I bet you also would acknowledge that wealthier
parents use both political power and the threat of choice to navigate
traditional systems for the benefit of their kids. I suspect you agree that not all TPS expenditures have been
wise, or for the benefit of students – indeed, you may even agree that public
sector traditional public schools have an extensive history of fiscal waste,
fraud, and abuse. I suspect you
also agree that public funding, multi-sector provision, and private citizen
choice works in some areas, such as public services in Denmark, or healthcare
provision (as opposed to healthcare finance) in the United States.
Is
that a fair summary, Jazzman? If
so, can you think of any compromises to recommend to policy-makers who might be
reading this exchange?
* * * *
Thank
you again for your platform and the patience of your audience.
I hope this has moved a few minds, or
at least opened up a few lines of communication.
[i] I agree
there remains the fiscal challenge of spreading fixed costs over fewer
students. As I’ve noted, this is a real issue, but it’s a very different and
more focused conversation than the skimming allegation.
Moreover, if we dive into the fiscal
data, I believe we’ll find the same result: that the aggregate impact of
charter expansion on TPS fiscal management is net positive, not net
negative.
We’ll save that for
another conversation, however.
[ii] When you
ask the question: “is this really the best we can do?”, you are setting up an
absurd standard.
By that standard,
**no action** would ever be taken, ever, because no single action is ever by
itself the best we can do.
The
question at hand is whether we should expand charters or not.
[iii] On height,
the question is not whether the gain would make you an NBA basketball player,
but whether most people would care. In the world of cosmetics, a product that
delivered an average height gain of one-third of an inch would become a
multibillion-dollar product. Also, when you double down on the Loveless /
Spielberg examples, you use final adult height, rather than what clinicians and
biostatisticians refer to as “height velocity” – i.e., how fast you grow.
Height velocity is the apt comparison for growth over a long period, and
standard deviations of height gain
are pretty wide.
[iv] Your
protests about my focus on Hispanic ELL are a little bit overwrought, as I
suspect you realize on reflection. As I have written in the past, this is the
national cohort relevant to my daughter’s friend from soccer, whose personal
story you entirely ignore in your rebuttal. It is also the most clear case for
charters, because these parents are least likely to have either voice or choice
to navigate TPS, so you’d expect charter gains to be especially stark.
To be clear, the Hispanic ELL
population sub-group is an aggregate result, as it includes the results from
those cities whose charters perform very poorly, as well as for those cities
whose charters perform well.
If I
had isolated only the better-performing cities or better-performing charters,
the result would be much greater.
[v] The cohorts
of students of color in poverty are the benchmark relevant to our debate, because
those are the students who are least well served in the status quo. Of course I
care about the other students, but those generally are not as poorly served in
the status quo.